Europe Needs a California Dream

Authors: Uri Dadush, Moises Naim
Originally published by the Wall Street Journal

At first glance California appears to be in the midst of an economic and fiscal crisis that dwarfs Europe’s. Its unemployment rate, now more than 12%, is one of the highest in the U.S. and nearly 3% more than the EU average; California’s home prices have dropped 34% since 2007, while in Europe the decline has been moderate; and over the last three years, the collapse of California’s tax receipts produced a cumulative budget deficit of about 40% of its revenues, more than twice that of Greece. California’s politics are as gridlocked as any in Europe. Political infighting left the state without a budget for the first 100 days of this year.

Paradoxically, despite this grim picture, it is actually Europe that should be envious of California. In fact, as countries in the euro area rethink the institutional arrangements that underpin their monetary union, there is a lot that Europeans could learn from the vicissitudes of America’s Golden State.

This year’s sovereign-debt crisis in the European periphery was triggered by the same global recession that engulfed California. The deeper roots of Europe’s woes, however, lie in the loss of competitiveness of Greece, Ireland, Italy, Portugal, and Spain relative to Germany and the European core. With growth stifled and debt rising rapidly, the overextended governments in these countries have lost the confidence of financial markets.

In California, this has not happened. Prices and wages in California have moved roughly in line with those of the rest of the U.S., whereas Greek and Italian labor costs, for example, have risen by more than 25% relative to Germany’s since they adopted the euro a decade ago. Financial markets are treating Californiawhose economy is larger than Spain’sfar more leniently than they treat Europe’s stricken countries. California’s debt trades at spreads less than 1% higher than those of AAA states, whereas the bonds of the aforementioned countries trade at an average 3.5% spread vis-à-vis Germany.

What explains this difference in performance in the face of similar shocks? A more resilient institutional design that will allow California to emerge from its crisis stronger and faster than Europe’s worst fiscal performers.

Despite its record budget shortfall, California’s debt is now less than 5% of its GDP. In contrast, the five most troubled European nations have debt burdens that are the roughly same size of their economy. This is because federal spending accounts for about 55% of all public expenditures in California while the state’s own spending is just 20% (the rest is spent by autonomous municipalities). So in California public spending footed by the state is only 7.9% of its GDP. In Europe, national spending typically represents about 50% of GDP while the budget of the European Commissionthe closest analog to a European federal governmentaccounts for just 1%.

The U.S. federal system thus ensured that the safety nets available to Californians continued to operate throughout the crisis even as its residents contributed less to it. Europe’s decentralized fiscal system guarantees no such stability. To be sure, a fiscally more centralized euro zone would also mean spreading countries’ debts and risks around. But California’s experience suggests that in a monetary union it is important to be able to pool risks: being part of a much larger entity that retains AAA rating and controls its currency reassures financial markets.

Importantly, state laws prevent California’s debt from spiraling out of control and require a balanced budget. The Financial Stability Pact, Europe’s closest equivalent, does not have the same force of law, and has been repeatedly and spectacularly flouted. And whereas in the United States there is no legal procedure to deal with the default of one of its states (it has never happened during the union’s 234 years), financial markets expect that the process would be handled by the federal government and that it would be modeled after the procedure that already exists for municipal bankruptcy (Chapter 9 of the bankruptcy code). If a European country defaulted, there is complete uncertainty about who would be in charge or how creditors would be treated, which makes the risk all the more unattractive.

Crashing California is also better suited to deal with economic shocks thanks to its labor-market flexibility: Employers can more easily reduce payrolls in a downturn, and wages adjust more rapidly. Moreover, though labor mobility across state lines in the U.S. has declined with the recession, workers there still move much more fluidly than across European frontiers. Partly because both workers and firms are exposed to more competition, American firms have restructured faster: U.S. GDP has declined by only 1.2% from the second quarter of 2008 through the second quarter of 2010, while European GDP fell by 3.2%. Meanwhile, since bottoming out in the second quarter of 2009, investment in the U.S. grew by 23% through the second quarter of this year, compared to a rise of 8% in the EU.

Though a U.S.like political union is not imaginable for Europe, the Continent can replicate some of the institutional arrangements that allowed California to better weather the storm. Improving labor-market flexibility, increasing the funds available to support stricken regions, adopting better rules that ensure and enforce fiscal discipline, and establishing a process to restructure sovereign debts are some of the innovations that would boost Europe’s resiliency to future shocks.

Some of these measures are now being hotly debated by EU leaders. Even if they are adopted, they will not fully immunize Europe against economic shocks. But without these reforms, there will surely be more pain than there needs to be.

Be the first to comment

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published.


*